Patent rites
Patents get a makeover
Santosh Rana has a type of blood cancer -- chronic myeloid leukaemia -- that was detected in early 2003. His doctors prescibed him an anti-cancer drug, Glivec. He could afford it, they said; the cost of treatment would come to between Rs 9,000 to Rs 12,000 per month. But then things changed. Out of the blue, in November 2003, Rana suddenly found he could not afford his cancer treatment anymore. The same drug now cost him Rs 1,20,000 per month.
His doctors explained that what had changed was that Novartis India had been granted exclusive marketing rights by the government. The company had also filed, and won, an injunction against all other Indian companies manufacturing a 'copycat' version of the drug. The very sort of drug that Rana was buying each month.
This was 2003. In 2005, the situation will change even further, as the government gets ready to pass the Patents (Amendment) Ordinance 2004. The Indian Patents Act 1970, was amended in 1999 and 2002, so that India could comply with the provisions set out by the Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (trips) agreement of the wto.
This agreement is meant to protect the rights of the inventors -- from drugs to seeds -- and builds in provisions that do not allow companies to sell what is known in the pharma parlance as 'copycat drugs'. The 1999 amendment provided for exclusive marketing rights, which gave the inventor company 5 years of protection. Now, with the proposed third amendment, this provision will be further tightened.
The ordinance of the government of India provides for product patents, instead of process patents. India's 1970 patent protection act, protected only the process involved in developing drugs and not the end product itself. Several Indian companies had innovated, by producing the same drug through a different process. These drugs, called generic versions, came at much lower costs. But while end users benefitted, the inventor companies cried foul, arguing that the costs of their invention were not paid. This loss, they said, would mean that they would not be able to invest further in drug research, and that would end up endangering even more lives.
Once the 3rd amendment is passed by the Indian Parliament, the business of generics would be out. The fact is that Indian companies have come to dominate the market in the past 30 years -- from a market share of 30 per cent in 1972 to controlling over 72 per cent of the domestic medicine market in 2004. Cipla's turnover, for instance, crossed Rs 2,000 crore in 2003-2004, a staggering 27 per cent increase in that year. Ranbaxy's turnover is much higher at Rs 5,000 crore. These earnings were predominantly from the 'generics' business but now strategies would need to change to meet the new situation.
The critical issue here is what all this would do to prices of drugs in a poor country like India. The fact is that Indian drug prices, which were among the highest in the world in the pre-1970s are among the lowest in the world currently. The fact also is that India is confronted with a double burden of disease -- traditional diseases like malaria to modern diseases like cancer. It has extremely poor people and with high health costs , it needs to worry about the 'affordability' of its medicines.
What's unclear is how the 'product patent' will affect vast numbers of people in the country. The supporters of big pharma say that the 3rd amendment will not mean much, because most people do not depend on 'patented' drugs for their ailments. They say, in fact, that the 3rd amendment will protect Indian companies that invest in discovering new products. Indian r&d in medicine will prosper. The country will become a global player in the pharma business and also comply with wto and not face the wrath of the us . All win-win they say.
But there are many greys. Nobody seems to know what all this will do to people's health, for there are no reliable estimations of the cost of drugs in relation to healthcare cost.
The fact also is that nobody really knows how many drugs will go under patents. The problem is that this will also depend on the definition of what can be patented and from the year when the patenting of the drug for its 20 year period begins. This is further complicated in the global world of global business we live in today. For instance, GlaxoSmithKline filed a patent for rosiglitazone -- an anti diabetic drug -- in the us; it was granted this in 1987. Technically, its patent would have run out in 2007. But the company filed and got a patent for the same drug in Brazil in 1997. Now, if the company were to use the validity of its Brazil patent to ask for a patent in India, and say it got this from the date of its application in 1997, the same drug could continue to be sold till 2017.
'Evergreening' is another problem. The same company, which holds the original patent, can add something new in the composition or change its mixture, which could allow it to get another patent for the same modified product. In 1992, the anti-diabetic drug of Glaxo secured a patent for its modified version under 'rosiglitazone maleate' and so extended the life of its original 1987 patent by another 5 years. While the first version would expire in 2007 in the us market, the second evolved version would expire in 2012. The us has adopted the practice (a loosely defined law helps) where, when a patent is close to expiry or even midway, the patent holders can develop different salts, mixtures, polymorphs, metabolites, hydrates, isomers and derivatives of the same molecule and extend the life of the patent. Low Cost Standard Therapeutics (locost), a Vadodara group working on consumer rights in the context of patents, feels, "Most research and development spending goes into producing 'me too' drugs -- these are slight variations on existing drugs which can then be patented as 'new' drugs and sold at high prices. Often these variations are no better than molecular manipulation or a mere addition of other unnecessary ingredients."
Lack of clarity in Indian law means that evergreening will happen in India as well. And the ambiguity that exists in definitions leaves the crucial decisions to the discretionary powers of the patent examiners, who are not prepared at all to deal with vast numbers of patent applications (see box : Indian Patent Office ). Lack of clear guidelines will only result in endless litigation, with every decision being challenged. The potential for this has already been seen with Exclusive Marketing Rights (emr), where four out of five decisions taken by the patent office are embroiled in high court cases. (An emr is similar to a patent; granted for a shorter duration, about 5 years; India was obliged to provide them as an interim measure prior to introducing product patents). Products involved in such litigation include imatinib mesylate, Novartis' anti-cancer drug and rosiglitazone, GlaxoSmithKline's anti-diabetic drug. Novartis was granted an emr , Glaxo wasn't. Yet, both cases managed to end up in court.
This is why the 'wording' of the patent amendment bill becomes critical. How does the amendment bill define the term 'innovation'? How does the amendment bill provide for 'compulsory licensing' so that there is restricted monopoly in the areas of health?
In Brazil, an invention is novel "if it does not form part of state of the art"; state of the art being defined as "to comprise everything made available to the public by means of a written or oral description, by use, or in any other way, before the filing date of the patent application." France and Pakistan broadly follow the Brazil definition, as do Thailand and uk. China is explicit: "Novelty means, before the date of filing, no identical invention or utility model has been publicly disclosed in publications in the country or abroad, or has been publicly used or made known to the public by any other means in the country, nor has any other person filed previously with the Patent Office, an application which described the identical invention or utility model and was published after the said date of filing."
The basic subject matter of what can be patented, such as pharmaceutical substances, is also somewhat ambiguous. Should it be restricted to new chemical entities (nce), that is to say, the basic chemical molecule that has a certain therapeutic effect? Or, should patenting also be allowed for novel drug delivery systems, basically new ways (such as patches or inhalers) of administering drugs?
And how about innovations like metabolites (a chemical compound created when the patient's body metabolises the active ingredient of a drug) or innovations like polymorphs (includes compounds forming a crystalline structure different from the original molecule)?
The People's Commission on the Review of Legislations amending Patents Act 1970, an independent group chaired by former prime minister I K Gujral, which has been monitoring the patent provisions, argues that the amendment is inadequate. They suggest that the definition of invention must include the concept of basic novel product or process. By restricting invention to basic novelty, it would regulate the applications for patents to a manageable level, argues the commission.
They also say that invention should be further defined to ensure that nothing that is already in the public domain, in the country or elsewhere in the world, is patented. In other words, we should innovate, like the Chinese and others have done, to ensure that we restrict the use of patents to what is legitimate and deserves protection. Patents should not become the route to increase the monopoly of the inventor.
The Indian Drug Manufacturers' Association (idma), the industry association that represents a segment of the industry, wants the amendment to restrict patenting to only nces, or a basic new molecule. Even when it comes to novel drug delivery, idma says that it should be restricted only if the invention is based on a new technology. "Only significantly novel inventions should be granted patents, and we should prevent marginal innovations from being patented," contends Nihchal Israni, chairperson, Intellectual Property Rights Committee, idma and chairman and managing director of Blue Cross Laboratories.
But there are other views. The Organisation of Pharmaceutical Producers of India (oppi), that represents the multinational corporation viewpoint, supports patenting of all of the above, including innovations like metabolites and polymorphs. "Incremental innovations are India's strength. Where it's a low hanging fruit, we should grab with both hands," argues Ajit Dangi, director-general, oppi.
This us-led approach of trips- plus has clearly found favour with the Indian government as well. But can it organise the market here? Does this market wish to be organised?
What will the disappearance of generics do to the price of drugs in the market? Nobody really knows. Nobody really knows how to track what is currently patented.
One way of estimating it could be to work backwards from what the us industry claims it's losing, if the generic market is allowed. The office of the us Trade Representative working hand in glove with Pharmaceutical Research and Manufacturers of America (ph rma), the us pharma industry group, estimates the us industry loses us$1.8 billion in revenues because of the lack of patent protection in India. That's around 40 per cent of the total Indian market of us$4.5 billion, or Rs 8,000 crore. "This figure may not be accurate because they may have valued it at their prices," clarifies D G Shah of Indian Pharmaceutical Alliance, a big Indian pharma grouping. "But our sources in Geneva tell us that phrma has claimed (unofficially) that 15 per cent of the Indian market, in terms of value, includes drugs under patent. This, if we calculate, would amount to Rs 3,000 crore," says Shah. So, potentially Rs 3,000 crore worth of drugs would get into a patent regime and their generic version would have to be scrapped.
The other indicator to estimate what could be the volumes of the patented drugs, currently used in the country, would be through the applications pending at the patent office. These are growing since the ordinance was passed. Last July, the Union ministry of commerce and industry told Parliament there were 4,792 pharma applications in the patent mail box. In February this year, the same ministry reported there were 5,636 such applications pending approval at the Indian Patent Office. But how many of these are really for new chemical entities, as allowed by the current amendment?
This, says industry, is the crux of the problem. The current amendment, which does not restrict patents to a new chemical entity, and in fact allows a dilution in the pre-grant opposition, may lead to huge distortions. This is further compounded by an inexpert patent office and will lead to many of these ostensibly new but actually evergreen applications being cleared; patents being granted. Many such products may already be in the market. "A number of pre-1995 molecules, even those discovered in 1970-75, can come under patents in India," cautions Shah.
Government has its own calculations. Kamal Nath, Union minister of commerce and industry, maintains prices will not spiral. In fact, he goes on to say categorically, research shows 97 per cent of the drugs are off-patent and that none of the 354 drugs in the Essential Medicines List are patented.
But questions still remain: "97 per cent of what?" ask industry and analysts. The number of total drugs sold in India? Or 97 per cent of the turnover of the industry not under patents? "There are 60,000 drugs sold on the market and if we were to calculate, based on the minister's assumption, then three per cent of that number is 2,000 drugs," points out Hamied. Who is to say which these 2,000 drugs are, and what their overall turnover is? Calculating further, three per cent of a Rs 20,000 crore industry would amount to a turnover of Rs 600 crore. The range is mindboggling.
If we take the different claims and their assumptions, there is a fair amount of divergence. While government claims this amendment would affect drugs worth Rs 600 crore, the us government and industry estimation puts it close to Rs 3,000 crore. Still, what does this do to price? After all, it can be argued that market conditions will not allow the companies to sell at much higher rates.
In other words, can we learn from the experience of other countries which have followed the us - trips approach? When the People's Commission used this indicator, they found the comparative prices of some drugs, sold in Pakistan and Indonesia, were between four to 29 times higher than India (see table: Contrasting drug prices). In a situation like this, the role of government is critical. But what are its options? How does it plan to restrict monopolies? Can it control the rise in prices of existing drugs or new products entering the market at high prices?
|
Another approach to limit the impact of monopolies is to allow more licenses for the same drug to be manufactured and sold. Licenses could come in three varieties -- voluntary, automatic or compulsory:
A voluntary license, as its name implies, is the result of a negotiated arrangement between the patent holder and any other party interested in commercialising the patented product. The patent holder is usually rewarded in the form of royalty payments at the agreed rate. Such an agreement does not require state intervention.
Automatic and compulsory licenses are measures employed by the State to protect the consumer. trips provides for compulsory licensing, which can be used by the government, in certain prescribed circumstances. For instance, if India decides that aids being a serious epidemic needs cheaper drugs, it could apply compulsory licenses so that industry can supply it generic drugs, even if patented drugs are available.
The existing law allows for compulsory licensing and the proposed amendment has added the provision to facilitate exports to those countries, "with limited or no manufacturing capacity". The conditions, under which compulsory licenses can be issued include shortages in availability, high prices and health emergencies as well as abusive practices. But again the question remains, will the government have the spunk to impose compulsory licenses against large pharma companies and large vested interests?
trips also says that if a patent holder refuses to deal on the terms and conditions offered by a domestic manufacturer, within a reasonable period, the government can go ahead with compulsory licenses. But this trips friendly provision, has for some reason, been ignored by the trips friendly government. Almost all patent acts provide for this. Another approach, less trips friendly, is to include a provision for automatic licenses, also known as license of right, allowing generic manufacturers to freely manufacture and sell a patented drug. The generic manufacturer has to pay a royalty to the patent holder, which is under a ceiling, defined by the government. Here, the royalty received by the innovator serves as a reward and an incentive for investment in r&d. Cipla advocates that the government should be free to grant automatic licenses for drugs required for cancer, malaria, hepatitis and other key diseases.
But the devil is in the detail. So, even as we have hesitantly accepted compulsory licenses, the patent law ensures that the procedure is so cumbersome that it is virtually impossible to use. The amendment does nothing to streamline this process.