A developmental code is needed
Policy changes in economic management usually have repercussions in the areas of ecology, social and gender equity. Looking back, the past 25 years of globalisation and liberalisation have had both positive and negative impacts. Avoidable controls have been removed, but there has also been liberalisation in handling our ecosystems, which has nearly endangered the livelihood security of the people dependent on natural resources.
The challenge ahead lies in harmonising economic progress with progress in human welfare, particularly with reference to the underprivileged sections of society. There should be a development code which gives overriding priority to both safeguarding environmental assets and promoting sustainable livelihoods. The United Nations Sustainable Development Goals provide guidelines for achieving a balance between economic development and ecological security. One of the goals where our country should pay particular attention is Goal 2 (Ending hunger, achieving food security and improving nutrition and promoting sustainable agriculture). Ultimately, we can see progress only if the greed of the rich is curbed and the genuine needs of the poor are met.
ANIL AGARWAL,
editor, Down To Earth
Two issues come to mind: one concerns resource use, the other concerns pollution and toxics. The pressure to generate foreign exchange will definitely have an impact on our land and forests. On the toxics side, liberalisation will mean that technology will come in without adequate checks. Economists tell us that the environment is an externality. The cost of damages is borne by future generations or by the powerless, namely the poor. Therefore, the argument is that we must internalise it. But any price is arrived at through negotiations between a buyer and a seller. In this case, who is the buyer of natural resources and who is the seller? We want more rapid growth. But who is going to control resources?
SUDIPTO MUNDLE,
Professor, National Institute of Public Finance and Policy
If there is no safety net, there will be an increase in the incidence of poverty and that will clearly increase environmental stress. If people are not able to use kerosene and coal, they are obviously going to collect more firewood. That, certainly, is going to happen in the short term.
L C JAIN,
former member, Planning Commission
We are going through a transition in which even those who are convinced that what they are doing is right don’t seem entirely sure whether they can control all the consequences. If better care of soil, water and vegetation is an essential part of our environmental defence system, then it’s not only a question of policy but also of the kind of institutions that are needed to promote this concern.
Y K ALAGH,
Professor of economics, Sardar Patel Institute of Economics
But, it’s not a question of institutions alone. It’s also a question of giving them correct indicators on scarcities and benefits, which is what a budget really does. I am arguing for planning. Planning does not necessarily mean centralised planning but it means knowledge-based indicators and institutional mechanisms which will facilitate decision-making. We should basically work towards an institutional system which takes environmental costs and profits into account.
JAIRAM RAMESH,
Officer-on-special duty, Planning Commission
The structural adjustment programme is trying—not very successfully as yet—to confine public investment to essential areas. You can call it privatisation but I think there is a common cause here between people who advocate more safety nets and what the government is trying to do. The question is not whether we should have interventions or not but what should be the modalities of that intervention.
(From ‘Will liberalisation destroy the environment?’ Down To Earth, May 31, 1992; designations as of May 31, 1992)